Let’s Bond Market Over Tea Shall We
By Melvin J. Howard
The beginning of the Boston Tea Party is often sourced to what the
Colonists felt was an unfair tax on tea. This is only partly true. The Tea
Party was a protest in reaction to a tax meant to help raise funds following
the French and Indian War. But the tax was also a political power move on
behalf of Parliament, meant to reassert control over the colonies, as well as
an economic decision designed to bail out the floundering East India Company, a
threshold of English commercial interests. After the long and costly war
between France and England, King George III and the British Parliament
implemented a tax to help raise money to pay off the massive debts incurred.
They chose to place this tax on tea sold in both England and in the English
Colonies. They were convinced that people would rather pay a tax than give up
their daily tea.
It was also an item that the colonies were required to import
only from England. Furthermore, the tax was a way to reign in the colonies, who
had been neglected during the long war, and remind them that their allegiance
belonged to England. One of the first persons to master the Bond market was Nathan
Rothschild. Master of universe
at that time, he boasted that he was the arbiter of peace and war, and that the credit of nations
depends upon his nod. So
just what are Bonds a Bond is
a debt security, in which the authorized issuer owes the holders a
debt and, depending on the terms of the bond, is obliged to pay interest. There
are many kinds of bonds but for this entry I will be focusing on Government
Bonds. Nathan Mayer Rothschild, founder
of the London branch of what was, for most of the nineteenth century, the biggest
bank in the world. But it was the bond market that
made the Rothschild family rich real rich.
Lord Rothschild, Nathan's
great-great-great-grandson. Said of Nathan he was 'short, fat, obsessive, extremely clever,
wholly focused I can't imagine he would have been a very pleasant
person to have dealings with. The Battle of
Waterloo was the culmination of more than two decades of intermittent conflict between
Britain and France. But it was more than a battle between two armies. It
was also a contest between rival financial systems: one, the French, which under
Napoleon had come to be based on plunder (the taxation of the conquered); the
other, the British, based on debt. Between 1793 and 1815 the British national debt increased by a factor of three to more than double
the annual output of the UK economy. This increase in the supply of bonds had weighed heavily on the London
market.
Now let’s jump to the other side of the
Atlantic to another war the Civil war in America and how the North really won.
The South's ability to manipulate the bond market depended on one
overriding condition that investors should be able to take physical
possession of the cotton, which underpinned the confederate bonds if the South
failed to make its interest payments. Collateral is; after all, only good if a creditor
can get his hands on it. And that is why the fall of New Orleans was the real turning point in
the American Civil War. With the South's main port in Union hands, any investor
who wanted to get hold of Southern cotton had to run the Union's naval blockade
not once but twice, in and out. Given the North's growing naval power in and around
the Mississippi, that was non-starter.
If the South had managed to keep New
Orleans until the cotton harvest had been offloaded to Europe, they might have
been able to
sell more cotton bonds in London. The Confederacy had miscalculated.
They had turned off the cotton tap, but then wasn’t able to turn it back on. By 1863 the mills of Lancashire
England had found new sources of
cotton in China, Egypt and India. And now investors were rapidly losing faith in the South's cotton-backed bonds.
The consequences for the Confederate economy were disastrous. With its domestic bond market exhausted and only two paltry foreign
loans, the Confederate government was forced to print unbacked paper dollars to pay for the war and its
other expenses, 1.7 billion
dollars' worth in all. Both sides in the Civil War had to print money. But by
the end of the war the Union's 'greenback'
dollars were still worth about 50 cents in gold, whereas the Confederacy's 'greybacks' were worth just one cent. The situation got worst by the ability of Southern states and municipalities to print
paper money of their own.
With ever more paper money
chasing ever fewer goods, inflation exploded. Prices in the South rose by around 4,000 per cent
during the Civil War. By contrast, prices in the North rose by
just 60 per cent. Even before the surrender of the principal Confederate armies in April 1865, the economy of the South was
collapsing, with hyperinflation
remember this word I will come back to it later. Was the partner of the North
in the defeat of the South. Those
who had invested in Confederate
bonds ended up losing their shirts. The North
pledged not to honor the debts of the South. In the end, there had been no option but to finance the
Southern war effort by printing
money. It would not be the last time in history that an attempt to buck the bond market would end
in ruinous inflation and military
humiliation. The fate of those
who lost their shirts on Confederate bonds was not especially unusual in the nineteenth century.
The Confederacy was far from the only
state in the Americas to end up disappointing its bondholders; it was merely the
northernmost delinquent. South of the Rio Grande, debt defaults and currency depreciation's verged
on the commonplace. Latin America in the nineteenth century in many ways
foreshadowed problems that would become almost universal in the middle of the twentieth century. Partly it was
because Latin American republics were among the first to discover that it was
relatively painless to default when a substantial proportion of bondholders
were foreign.
It was no mere accident that the first great Latin American debt crisis
happened as early as 1816, when Peru, Colombia, Chile, Mexico, Guatemala and Argentina
all defaulted on loans issued in London just a few years before.
But by the later nineteenth century,
countries that defaulted on their debts risked economic sanctions, the
imposition of foreign control over their
finances and even, in at least five cases, military intervention. Defeat itself had a high price. All sides
had reassured taxpayers and
bondholders that the enemy would pay for the war. Now the bills
fell due take Berlin Germany for instance. One way to understand the post-war
hyperinflation was a form of state bankruptcy. Those who had bought war bonds had invested in a
promise of victory; defeat and
revolution represented a national insolvency, the brunt of which
necessarily had to be borne by the Germans creditors. At the conference at Versailles,
which imposed an unspecified reparations liability on the fledgling
Republic the total indemnity was finally fixed in 1921, the Germans found themselves
saddled with a huge external debt with a nominal capital value of 132, billion 'gold marks' (pre-war marks),
equivalent to more than three times national income. Although not
all this new debt was immediately interest-bearing, the scheduled
reparations payments accounted for
more than a third of all hail Hitler’s expenditure in 1921 and 1922.
Hyperinflation seemed to be the word of the day after
the First World War. Austria - as well as the newly independent Hungary and Poland
- also suffered comparably bad currency collapses between 1917 and
1924. In the Russian case, hyperinflation came after the Bolsheviks
had defaulted outright on the entire Tsarist debt. Bondholders
would suffer similar fates in the aftermath of the Second World War, when
Germany, Hungary and Greece all saw their currencies and bond markets
collapse. It could be easy to
associate hyperinflation with the costs of losing world wars; it would be
relatively easy to understand. Yet there is a caveat in more recent times, a
number of countries have been driven to default on their debts. Either
directly by suspending interest payments, or indirectly by debasing the currency in which the
debts are denominated.
There is a slight gamble involved when an
investor buys a bond. Part of that gamble is that an upsurge in
inflation will not consume the value of the bond's annual interest
payments. If inflation goes up to ten per cent and the value of a fixed rate interest
is only five, then that basically means that the bond holder is falling
behind inflation by five per cent.' As we have seen, the danger that rising
inflation poses is that it erodes the purchasing power of both the capital sum
invested and the interest
payments due. And that is why, at the first whiff of higher inflation, bond prices tend to fall. In 1975, as inflation soared around the world, the bond
market made the casino’s look
like a pretty safe place to invest your money. At that time when US inflation was surging into double digits, peaking at just fewer than 15 per
cent in 1980. That was perhaps the worst bond bear market in history.' To
be precise, real annual returns on U.S. government bonds in the 1975 were minus 3 percent, almost as
bad as during the inflationary
years of the world wars. Today, only a handful of countries have inflation
rates above 10 per cent and only
one, Zimbabwe, is afflicted with hyperinflation.'"" But back in 1979 at least seven countries had an annual
inflation rate above 50 per cent and more than sixty countries,
including Britain and the United
States, had inflation in double digits. Among the countries worst affected,
none suffered more severe long-term damage than Argentina.
Inflation has come down partly because many
of the items we buy, from clothes to computers, have got cheaper as a
result of technological innovation and the relocation of production to low-wage economies in
Asia. It has also been reduced because of a worldwide transformation in monetary
policy, which began with the monetarist-inspired increases in short-term
rates implemented by the Bank of England and the Federal Reserve in late 1975 and
early 1985. Also trade unions have become less powerful. Loss-making state
industries have been privatized. But, perhaps most importantly of all, the
social constituency
with an interest in positive real returns on bonds has grown. A rising share
of wealth is held in the form of private pension funds and other savings
institutions that are required, or at least expected, to hold a high proportion of their assets in
the form of government bonds and other fixed income securities. With every
passing year, the proportion of the population living off the income from such
funds goes up, as the share of retirees’ increases. In a graying society, there is a huge and
growing need for fixed income securities, and for low inflation to
ensure that the interest they pay retains its purchasing power. As
more and more people leave the workforce, recurrent public sector deficits
ensure that the bond market will never be short of new bonds to sell.